WOW !! MUCH LOVE ! SO WORLD PEACE !
Fond bitcoin pour l'amélioration du site: 1memzGeKS7CB3ECNkzSn2qHwxU6NZoJ8o
  Dogecoin (tips/pourboires): DCLoo9Dd4qECqpMLurdgGnaoqbftj16Nvp


Home | Publier un mémoire | Une page au hasard

 > 

From pricing to rating structured credit products and vice-versa

( Télécharger le fichier original )
par Quentin Lintzer
Université Pierre et Marie Curie - Paris VI - Master 2 2007
  

précédent sommaire suivant

Bitcoin is a swarm of cyber hornets serving the goddess of wisdom, feeding on the fire of truth, exponentially growing ever smarter, faster, and stronger behind a wall of encrypted energy

3.1.2 Moody's Metric and coherent risk measures

We now temporarily put the risk-neutral measure aside and focus on the historical probability measure. Moody's uses the same methodology to rate CPDO and CPPI/DPPI products. It estimates the expected present value of the loss function L(M) through Monte-Carlo simulations under the historical probability measure.

Definition 2. Moody's expected discounted loss

Let t E I = {0, ät, .., kät, .., T} describe the discrete time scale with T the maturity of the deal. Let Xt := (X(1)

t , .., X(p)

t ) be the p-vector of risk factors observed as of date t. We introduce the filtration (Ft){t?I} defined as ?t E I, Ft := ó (Xu,u E I,u = s). We further define the three stopping times (r, r, r):

r := inf{s = 0, NPV (s) = TRV (s)}

r := inf{s = 0, NPV (s) = BF(s)} A T r := r A r

We then express Moody's risky discount factor DF(M) as a function of the EURIBOR/LIBOR rate curve and of the senior spread s served to the investor:

?t E I, DF(M)(t) :=

t-1Y
i=0

1

1 + ät(EUR(iät, (i + 1)ät) + s)

>1p i=1 L(M) L(M) = i

p

+

ót99%

vp

Then, under the historical probability measure, Moody's expected discounted loss L(M) is given below:

[ ]

L(M) := E 1{ô<ô} [A(1 - sl) - max(NP V (r), BF (r)) + DI(r)]+ DF (M)(r)

where sl is the detachment point in % of the subordinated note.

In practise, Moody's uses an unbiased empirical estimator of L(M), L(M) defined as:

where t99% := Ö-1(99%), p is the number of Monte-Carlo simulations, L(M)

i is the

loss calculatd on the ith scenario and ó is the standard error of (L(M)

1 , .., L(M)

p ).

Moody's then maps that value L(M) and the maturity of the deal T against a positive real scale S = [0, 21] through a function MM called «Moody's Metric»:

MM : [0, 1] × R+ -? [0, 21]

(x,t) i-? MM(x,t)

We shall now describe how the Moody's Metric mapping function works. We first define the letter-to-integer mapping function R:

R : {Aaa,Aa1,..,Ca,C} -? {1,..,21}

m -? R(m)

The discrete mapping table is given below:

Rating-Figure

Rating-Letter

1

Aaa

2

Aa1

3

Aa2

4

Aa3

5

A1

6

A2

7

A3

8

Baa1

9

Baa2

10

Baa3

11

Ba1

12

Ba2

13

Ba3

14

B1

15

B2

16

B3

17

Caa1

18

Caa2

19

Caa3

20

Ca

21

C

Figure 3.1: Moody's rating conversion table

We shall now define the discrete function EL that maps the integer equivalent of a rating category and a maturity with a percentage expected loss:

EL : {1, .., 21} × {1, .., T} -? [0, 1]

(m, t) '-? EL(m, t)

Moody's calibrates the function EL on historical default data by using the cohort method.

Figure 3.2: Moody's idealized EL values by rating category and tenor

We shall then define EL, the time-continuous version of EL function obtained by linearly interpolating EL between two discrete integer dates:

EL : {1,..,21} x [0,T] -*[0,1]

(m, t) i-* (t + 1 - [t])EL(m, [t]) + (t - [t])EL(m, [t] + 1)

Let us now define the reverse mapping function F -1 that transforms any percentage loss level and tenor into a rating:

F -1 : [0, 1] x [0, T] -* {1, .., 21}

(x,t) -* min{m E {1,..,21}| EL(m,t) = x}

We finally give the expression of the Moody's Metric function MM: Definition 3. Moody's Metric

?x E [0,1],?t E [0,T],

EL(F -1(x, t), t))

ln x - ln (

MM(x, t) := F -1(x, t) + ln ( EL(F -1(x, t) + 1, t)) - ln ( EL(F-1(x, t), t))

In other words, the Moody's Metric can be seen as a standardized continuous scale that allows to compare expected loss levels for different tenors. We shall now take a closer look at the notion of risk measure and understand to what extent it makes sense to use the expected loss as a proxy for measuring risk.

Definition 4. Coherent Risk Measure

Let C denote a set of random variables representing all possible risky positions and L E C be a random variable whose range of values represents possible losses from any given risky position. We define the risk measure function p as a mapping from C to R. The risk measure p is coherent if it is:

i) monotonous: ?X, Y ? G, X = Y p(X) = p(Y )

ii) positively homogeneous: ?X ? G, ?h > 0, hX ? G and p(hX) = hp(X)

iii) sub-additive: ?X, Y ? G, X + Y ? G and p(X + Y ) = p(X) + p(Y )

iv) translation invariant: ?X ? G, ?a ? R s.t. X + a ? G, p(X + a) = p(X) + a

Proposition 4.

If G+ is a set of non-negative random variables, interpreted as a loss from a risky position, then expected value is a coherent risk measure:

?X ? G+, p(X) := E[X]

Proof. Properties (i),(ii), (iii) and (iv) immediately result from the expectation's linearity.

Unlike E[X], the Moody's Metric MM(X, t), where X is a positive random variable that takes its values in [0, 1], is not a coherent risk measure: though it is clearly monotonous and subadditive (because MM(., t) is increasing and concave), it is neither positively homogeneous, nor translation invariant.

précédent sommaire suivant






Bitcoin is a swarm of cyber hornets serving the goddess of wisdom, feeding on the fire of truth, exponentially growing ever smarter, faster, and stronger behind a wall of encrypted energy








"I don't believe we shall ever have a good money again before we take the thing out of the hand of governments. We can't take it violently, out of the hands of governments, all we can do is by some sly roundabout way introduce something that they can't stop ..."   Friedrich Hayek (1899-1992) en 1984